The most incisive guide to issues facing the American family today . . . An invaluable resource for anyone wishing to stay on the cutting edge of research on family trends.

-W. Bradford Wilcox
Associate Professor of Sociology, University of Virginia 

February 26, 2019

The Topic: AOC and Population Control

The News Story: Rep. Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez: ‘Is it OK to still have children?'

The New Research: Roots of Recession

 

The News Story: Rep. Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez: ‘Is it OK to still have children?'

In a line that is not today as radical as it once was, New York Representative Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez took to her Instagram account over the weekend to ponder on the morality of childbearing.

While chopping sweet potatoes and pouring white wine, she reminded her viewers that “Our planet is going to face disaster if we don’t turn this ship around.” Part of the solution may be, she hints, that we consider some level of population control. “And so it’s basically like, there is a scientific consensus that the lives of children are going to be very difficult and it does lead, I think young people, to have a legitimate question. Ya know, should—is it okay to still have children?”

But while zealots like AOC have been beating the “population bomb” drum for decades now, research continues to suggest that without an increasing population, mankind’s future looks bleak indeed. 

(Source: FOX News, “Rep. Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez: ‘Is it OK to still have children?’” February 26, 2019.)

 

The New Research: Roots of Recession

For decades, population-control zealots warned of dire consequences of more babies—famine, poverty, natural disaster, etc. Now, research warns about the social and economic risks of historically low birth rates in many industrialized nations. Two recent studies reflect those concerns.

The first of these is the effort of Edward Crenshaw of Ohio State and Kristopher Robison of Northern Illinois University to reintroduce sociological theories as explanations of economic growth. Using pooled time-series analysis of changes in real gross domestic product per capita of more than 100 nations for the years 1970 and 2000, their study finds that population growth is an independent and necessary driver of economic and social development: “The long-run consequences of population growth for societal advancement have been positive rather than negative. Historical population density clearly exerts a robust, positive effect on contemporary economic growth rates.”

Debunking Mathusian fiction that fertility growth leads to “adversity, poor labor absorption, lagging capital formation, and poor macroeconomic performance,” Crenshaw and Robison’s results reveal quite the opposite. “As a form of societal investment, long-run population increase forces adaptive differentiation and interdependency on societies, complexities that lead to higher surpluses and social-spatial characteristics that predispose these societies to accelerated integration into the modern world.” Moreover, their study explains why fertility decline might be beneficial in the short-term but “disastrous” over time: “Rapid growth in the dependent population may retard economic growth, but it probably does not actually impoverish a society. . . . If a society can hold its own economically during its baby booms, then it stands a good chance of ratcheting up its economic activity when these children finally enter the labor force.”

Another study, by S. Philip Morgan and Heather Rackin of Duke University, highlights more the fact of population change than its correlation with economic or social development. They put on the table for all to see the worldwide transition, since 1960, from high fertility to fertility decline. They come to the conclusion: “No twentieth century change has more profound implications or been more dramatic than fertility changes.” Among the determinants of fertility decline the Duke researchers identify is the rising median age of childbearing, a behavioral shift common to all Western nations. They concede that such postponement can be more dramatic in some countries, but nonetheless claim it can reduce the Total Fertility Rate of a country by 10 to 20 percent for up to two or three decades. It also raises the risks of difficulties in conceiving children and carrying them to term—and leads couples to revise downward (never upward) their intended fertility: “Thus the demographers’ adage: fertility delayed is (partly) fertility foregone.”

Given the findings of these two studies, is it any wonder that economic forecasters give increasingly dire predictions?

(Source: Bryce J. Christensen and Robert W. Patterson, “New Research,” The Family in America 24.4 [Fall 2011]. Study: Edward Crenshaw and Kristopher Robison, “Socio-demographic Determinants of Economic Growth: Age-Structure, Preindustrial Heritage, and Sociolinguistic Integration,” Social Forces 88.5 [July 2010]: 2217–40, and S. Philip Morgan and Heather Rackin, “A Half Century of Fertility Change,” Journal of Comparative Family Studies 41.4 [Summer 2010]: 515–35.)